Why Is The Problem Of Resolving Climate Change A Classic Case Of The Tragedy Of The Commons?

Table of Contents (click to expand)

Climate change is certainly a tragedy of the commons, as no one really knows who to blame, and the necessary collective action requires an unprecedented momentum that is not building at the pace our survival demands. Without collective efforts, since the costs and benefits are not linearly aligned, it is difficult to bring about the adequate mitigation of climate change.

The Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC) was formed in 1988. This was the first time it was formally recognized that climate change had become a global issue and required collective efforts to be resolved. The IPCC was jointly established by the United Nations Environment Programme (UNEP) and the World Meteorological Organization to collaborate on monitoring and evaluating climate change.

It has been more than three decades and many conferences on climate change since 1988, yet the problem of climate change only seems to get more severe every year. Whether it is rising temperatures, forced migration, erratic storms or rising sea levels, the problem has seeped into our day-to-day vocabulary and lived experiences.

It is estimated that, on average, a temperature rise of 1°C in a given country and year causes per capita income to fall by, on average, 1.4 per cent. That said, this decline may not necessarily be linear, nor will it uniformly impact every individual’s income. 


Recommended Video for you:



What Is The Tragedy Of The Commons?

In economics, the tragedy of the commons is applied when a resource does not have clearly defined property rights. Due to a lack of ownership, the resource tends to get overused and mismanaged. Moreover, since there is no one to safeguard its usage, it commonly leads to depletion or degradation due to over-usage.

Polar,Bear,Sow,And,Cub,Walk,On,Ice,Floe,In
Increasing concentration of carbon in the air gets trapped in the atmosphere and leads to global warming, which melts icecaps. (Photo Credit : FloridaStock/Shutterstock)

Think of a resource such as a lake. A lake is usually not owned by one individual or entity. That lake would usually be subjected to multiple people using it for different purposes, which could range from bathing to releasing effluents. Since there is no control over who does what, so long as everyone benefits in the short run, no one bothers anyone else. Poor maintenance further worsens this situation, which often leads to either the drying up of lakes or of a space being unfit for human use.

The tragedy of the commons is commonly used in environmental economics to describe similar situations, especially in the case of natural resource management, as there are no clearly defined property rights. These resources’ typical end is being depleted or being made unfit for use by humans and animals, which further threatens sustainability.

There are no property rights in nature! All commonly owned resources are susceptible to the phenomenon of climate change, whether it’s a raging river or vast swaths of grazing land. Combine the entire ecosystem, and this becomes Nature!

From a very individualistic standpoint, there is no incentive for anyone to pause their consumption, unless it is expensive for them to continue doing so. Any step towards climate change must be consistent, and the change itself will still take years to reflect.

Greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions are the leading cause of climate change. Even in GHG, there is a specific focus on the reduction of carbon dioxide. Even if everyone decides to stop producing emissions today, climate change would not cease immediately; only its pace would slow down. The damage is done.

Years of emitting these gases have trapped them in our atmosphere, the impact of which we will still need to withstand. Therefore, any effort in this direction calls for long-term commitments.

Any single nation promising to take steps would be insufficient unless there is a collective step by all countries in the same direction. Here is where the politics of climate change enters the story, as all nations do not face the consequences of climate change equally. Moreover, every nation does not have the same capacity and knowledge to mitigate the consequences. Developed nations are far more equipped to deal with the problem, as compared to developing nations.

Therefore, it becomes imperative for everyone to have an equal foot in solving this issue. Collective action requires cooperation, monitoring, collective enforcement and the contribution of funds to manage this issue.

Reducing emissions will also mean a hit to most countries’ GDP. This is a risk that developing countries are not willing to bear. However, since the beginning of the 21st century, developing countries are the highest emitters of GHG due to increasing population, as well as the concentration of manufacturing-intensive activities.

Transitioning to greener practices requires technology and research, which requires funding. Mitigating the effects of climate change, while not hurting job seekers and economic growth, has thus far been a challenge that developing countries are not willing to take on. Developed nations had their period of growth during the era of industrialization, the gains from which they continue to reap, as compared to developing nations.

Dhaka, Bangladesh - July 21, 2020 Vehicles try to drive through a flooded street in Dhaka.
Erratic weather changes have now become a common phenomena. Who creates these emissions and who pays the price for it has always been a grey and controversial area. (Photo Credit : Sk Hasan Ali/Shutterstock)

Most democratic governments last for about five to six years in a country. Other commitments, such as fulfilling short-term electoral promises, will therefore take priority over long-term sustainability concerns. Since it is also a multipolar world, negotiations between countries to start managing an issue take longer than expected.

Additionally, since mitigation has lagged behind effects, countries have no strong incentive to tackle climate change as an immediate problem. The costs and benefits of mitigation and conservation would also be unevenly borne and shared. Taking collective action with the required momentum thus becomes a hefty and seemingly impossible task.

What Is The Impact Of Market-oriented Approaches Towards Climate Change Mitigation?

Most standard policies and approaches towards climate change mitigation have been primarily done through carbon pricing, whether through a carbon tax, carbon credits or carbon permits. All three are different ways of using price signals via markets to tackle the leading contributor of climate change–carbon.

Various empirical studies have shown governments the benefit of charging a price to emitters in order to discourage emissions. Market-oriented policies via pricing are also comparatively better than government-regulated policies, as it adds to the administrative burden and increases costs.

Since the effects of climate change are distributed unevenly, large emitters are able to pay the price and get away with their actions. This has a disproportionate effect on households with low income or industries with low capital. This further widens the gaps between haves and have-nots. The “polluter pays” principle tends to worsen inequality, as there would be no negative impact on the generator, so long as they are paying the price for it.

Carbon,Capture,Concept.,Natural,Carbon,Sinks.,Mangrove,Trees,Capture,Co2
Forests act as natural carbon sinks by absorbing carbon from the atmosphere. (Photo Credit : Fahroni/Shutterstock)

Powerful industries can get away with this and continue conducting business as usual. At the same time, since it persists in the atmosphere, the effects will still be borne by anyone who cannot pay to bear it.

Since the consequences of climate change cannot be predicted, it is imperative to find better measures to tackle the problem. The underlying belief in any market-based approach is that costs and benefits can be ascertained. Climate change is a type of problem for which the scale and magnitude of the consequences are entirely unknown. Hence, quantifying and monetizing it will not solve the problem, as that sort of capitalist-minded approach is what got us into this mess in the first place. 

While pricing may portray a sense of free markets, does it really hold the solution? On the other hand, while pricing may not be the best solution, it’s the only predominant solution we currently have. Hence the quandary—and the tragedy—of the commons. 


References (click to expand)
  1. Economics of Climate Change | US EPA.
  2. The Emissions Database for Global Atmospheric Research.
  3. Economic Development in an Era of Climate Change.